So my previous post on social status was recently treated to a review/critique by Scott Alexander over at Slate Star Codex.
I expect most of my readers are already big fans of Scott's blog (as am I). But for those of you who somehow aren't aware of it: SSC is phenomenal. It's one of the most original, insightful, and engaging blogs on the Internet. Please, do yourself a favor and check it out.
Anyway, in my original post I tried to make three main points about social status:
- It's not a single phenomenon, but rather two: dominance and prestige. These two systems are more-or-less distinct, and it's useful to think about them separately.
- Dominance can be understood from the top-down, but prestige needs to be understood from the bottom-up — by focusing on admiration, i.e., the way we fawn over people we respect.
- Admiration evolved to help us curry favor with actual or potential teammates. It's the price we pay to remain in the good graces of prestigious individuals — to earn a spot on their team and/or keep them happy as a teammate.
(All of this, I hasten to add, is cribbed from Jean-Louis Dessalles.)
Scott seems on board with 1 and 2, less on board with 3. Yes, he says, admiration often seems to work as a way of sucking up to teammates, but there are also a lot of cases where it doesn't make sense:
- David Bowie. When we — Bowie's admirers — lavish praise on him, what exactly are we hoping to accomplish? What group or team are we trying to keep him on, exactly? Are we hoping he stays in the West — rather than taking his musical talents to North Korea, say? Clearly not.
- Elon Musk or Justin Bieber. These celebrities are admired by millions (if not billions) of people. Each admirer stands an extremely slim chance of ever meeting, let alone teaming up with Musk or Bieber. So what's the point of admiring them?
- The Koch brothers. Depending on your politics, you may think poorly of the Koch brothers. If, however, you happened to sit next to them on a plane, you might still treat them with respect, i.e., the way you'd treat a prestigious person you actually like. But why suck up to people you don't actually admire?
- Helen Keller. Keller learned language, and even learned to speak, despite being blind and deaf from a very young age. Certainly this is impressive, and we admire her for it, wholeheartedly — but she's still pretty impaired. By admiring her, are we really trying to court her as a teammate? Presumably we'd be better served directing our admiration at someone with more complete faculties.
I continue to believe that admiration makes sense in each of these cases, and I'll address them more fully in a moment. But the bigger problem, I think, is that I did a mediocre job of explaining Dessalles' theory. So let me try again, using fresh language.
Dessalles' theory of prestige (take 2)
Admiration and prestige-seeking are two complementary teaming instincts.
(By "teaming," here, I'm referring to the game of coalition politics. But politics is a dirty word, and even though we're engaged in political behavior all the time, we don't think of it as "political." So I prefer to use softer language.)
In Dessalles' theory, the teams we care about are groups small enough for everyone to know everyone else and keep tabs on their behavior. We might also call them alliances, cliques, gangs, or coalitions. Even a pair of friends, it should be noted, is considered a "team" for our purposes here; it's just a degenerate team of size two. Each of us, of course, is simultaneously a member of many different (but partially-overlapping) teams.
For the sake of throwing out a number, we might cap a "team" at something like 10 or 20 members. It's not that our teaming instincts completely fail us at larger scales (like firms, nations, or a team like "the West"), but they're designed to work best at smaller scales.
From an individual's perspective, teaming instincts help solve a number of related problems[1]:
- How to join up with a team (ideally a worthy one) and convince them to accept you.
- How to attract other members to the team (ideally people who are competent and useful).
- How to remain in the team's good graces, so as not to get kicked out.
- How to secure for yourself a reasonable share of the team's spoils. Spoils are whatever resources or benefits the team works together to acquire. For a firm, its spoils are its profits. For a prison gang, spoils include physical protection and access to black market transactions. For a coalition of our forager ancestors (especially a sub-group coalition), spoils probably included food, mating opportunities, support from teammates during conflicts with non-teammates, and support during times of illness or injury.
In this context, a person's prestige is the measure of her value to a team (in the eyes of its members). If she has lots of prestige, it's because she's (perceived to be) better at most facets of teaming and teamwork. As a joiner, she'll be more attractive to existing teams. Within a team, she'll be more productive and therefore more worthy of her teammates' admiration. This, in turn, means she'll deserve a larger share of the spoils and will be less likely to get kicked off the team. She will also, simply by being on a team, make it more attractive to outsiders who might consider joining it.
So we seek prestige in order to raise our value on the teaming market, and we admire others as a way of bribing them to join (or stay on) the team. Prestige is our price, and admiration our method of payment.
It's important to note that in healthy, functioning teams, admiration is paid all around. Every teammate admires every other teammate — not equally, of course, but enough to keep the team together. More prestigious team members receive the most admiration, but even the least prestigious members get their share, as long as they remain in good standing.
This kind of mutual admiration, in fact, is the very mechanism by which teams divvy up the spoils. Everyone needs to get paid, somehow, and admiration (commensurate with prestige) is how we do it.
Incidentally, we can reformulate this in the language of friendship rather than teams.
Due to natural variation, people differ in their personal qualities, and some people make better friends/allies than others. A prestigious individual, then, is someone many others would like to be friends with, someone highly sought after as a friend. And this is where market dynamics take over. A person has only so much friendship to offer; supply is limited. So when the demand goes up, the price has to go up too. Prestigious individuals, then, are those who can command a high price for their friendship.
Now consider the problem of how to make and keep a friend. To earn someone's friendship, you need to make it worth his while. If the two of you are equally prestigious (equally valuable on the friendship market), you can simply barter in kind: your friendship for his. But if he's more prestigious than you, your friendship alone won't pay for his, and you'll have to make up the difference somehow. Those additional payments are what we've been calling admiration.
Back to Bowie (and friends)
I hope the explanation above was clear enough. Now, in light of it, what are we to make of our admiration for David Bowie? If we somehow managed to meet him, why would we be so eager to charm and flatter him?
It's not that we're trying to keep him on Team USA or Team "The West." Instead, we cozy up to him hoping he'll have a spot for us on Team Bowie; we're trying to befriend him personally. Why? Because being friends with a rockstar has its perks: epic parties, beautiful people, the latest designer drugs. Maybe he'll invite us backstage at his next show, for example, where we'll meet some cute girl or guy or get to rub shoulders with influential people.
Bottom line: David Bowie has a lot of resources, especially in the form of social capital, and would therefore make a great friend or ally. That's why we pay him in respect and admiration.
The Koch brothers. Assuming you don't like the Koch brothers, why treat them nicely if you happen to sit next to them on a plane?
Well, first of all, it's possible you'd actually snub them — if you really hated them, or really wanted to signal your righteousness to others. But if you're even slightly open to them as potential allies, as people you might personally befriend, their extreme prestige makes them worth treating well. Who knows what might happen if they take a liking to you. They might buy you a few drinks, for example, or offer you a ride home in their limo, or put you in touch with one of their influential friends who can help you on a project.
When you're nice to people, they tend to be nice in return. And when you're nice to high-status people, their niceness-in-return can be very nice indeed.
Elon Musk and Justin Bieber. Why do millions of people admire these celebrities that they'll never meet in person?
Here's how I would parse the situation.
First we need to distinguish between admiring someone in person, by deferring to them in concrete social situations, and admiring someone from afar, simply by thinking or speaking highly of them. Dessalles' theory applies only to in-person admiration. Long-distance admiration — like the kind we direct at Musk or Bieber — is something else entirely.
One possible explanation for long-distance admiration is that it helps us keep track of people who are worth admiring up close, in case we ever get the chance. And since long-distance admiration doesn't cost much, why not?
But this doesn't explain the intensity of the admiration that Musk and Bieber arouse in us; it doesn't explain why we become such rabid fans. So Scott suggests there might be group-signaling effects here, and I think he's right. By gushing about Elon Musk on my Facebook account, for example, I'm not trying to tee up a friendship with the man himself. (As it happens, we aren't FB friends.) Instead, it's more likely that I'm signaling to other Musk supporters — showing that I'm aligned with them and their values, for example, or that I'm smart and enlightened enough to appreciate Musk's contributions to the world.
In other words, Musk himself — the man on the hill — isn't the primary target of my long-distance admiration, but rather the people down here in my local social circle.
All this group signaling works to create a kind of cult[2] around the admired figure. But note that cult objects aren't always living, breathing humans. We also get whipped into a frenzy of group signaling around:
- Dead people like Jesus, Confucius, and Shakespeare.
- Abstract symbols like "God," "America," and "Apple."
- Concrete symbols like idols, totems, and flags.
- Values or ideals like liberty, justice, and love.
Elon Musk, then, is simultaneously a living person and a symbol representing the ideals of science, entrepreneurship, progress, etc. Insofar as he's a person, we pay respect in the hope of befriending him, i.e., earning a spot on Team Musk. Insofar as he's a symbol, we pay respect to him (or more precisely, to the idea of him) for the same reason we kneel before any altar: to curry favor with fellow worshippers.
In a cult of personality, these two processes overlap and reinforce each other. But I contend that they can and should be analyzed separately.
Helen Keller. Keller has been dead almost 50 years, so most of our current admiration for her is necessarily cultic. But even while she was alive, she was quite prestigious. Was it simply because she had an inspiring life story? Did people simply fetishize her as a symbol of perseverance?
I might have thought so. But after reading her Wikipedia page, a New Yorker piece about her, and Mark Twain's high praise for her, I have to conclude that she was genuinely impressive. She wasn't just a public curiosity — "that blind deaf girl who learned to speak." She was also a prolific author (12 books!), a world-famous public speaker, and an energetic political activist. She campaigned aggressively for radical causes like women's suffrage, birth control, and pacifism, and was influential enough that some people found it necessary to attack her for her views. She even helped found the ACLU.
I'm sure Keller capitalized plenty on her life story, but the point is she was very successful at it, and would have made a valuable ally.
A final thought
As I write this, it occurs to me that loyalty interacts with prestige in a way that illuminates both phenomena.
Within an existing team (including friendship "teams" of size two), your prestige reflects your value to your teammates. More precisely, it's the expected value of all your future contributions to the team — your NPV, if you will.
Now, in light of this, how might you go about increasing your prestige?
One strategy is to improve yourself — by learning new skills, for example — so that you'll be able to accomplish things of greater value. You thereby increase the expected size of your future contributions to the team.
But there's another, complementary strategy: try to increase the expected number of your future contributions. How? By convincing your teammates that you're likely to stick around longer.
The transaction is simple. In return for your loyalty, you earn your teammates' trust. And the interesting thing about trust — arguably, the essential thing — is that it isn't portable. When you leave a team, you can take everything else with you (skills, knowledge, money), but all that accumulated trust stays behind.
In other words, prestige has two components: a general-purpose "global" component and a team-specific "local" component. Global prestige includes everything valued on the outside market: skills, knowledge, money, relationships with outsiders. Local prestige includes everything not transferable to the outside market — trust, relationships with teammates, and team-specific knowledge and skills.
I think this helps explain why loyalty-signaling practices are so powerful, and produce such dramatic effects. Watch how loyalty-signaling can quickly escalate out of control:
- We begin with an initiate, who wishes to raise his value by demonstrating loyalty to his group. Words aren't enough: he needs to make honest (costly) commitments, i.e., by doing things that make it harder for him to leave the group. Techniques here include: severing ties with outsiders, doubling down on relationships with insiders, and undertaking lifestyle changes (diet, clothes, living arrangements) that make it harder to interact with the outside world.
- In return for these demonstrations of loyalty, the initiate is rewarded with trust, i.e., local prestige — something that increases his value within the group, but which has no benefit to him if he decides to leave. In other words, his reward for binding himself to the group is... something that further binds him to the group.
- Unfortunately local prestige, like global prestige, is a zero-sum game. So in order to compete for it, team members need to out-do each other, e.g., with even more extreme loyalty displays. This kind of competition is similar to what we find in any other prestige tournament (art, music, sports, academia, etc.). The main difference lies in the direction competitors are selling themselves for prestige: artists and athletes sell themselves outward, while loyalty-signaling teammates sell inward.
- Finally, if processes 1–3 are strong enough, most group members will end up fairly committed to the group. They'll draw their admiration largely from other group members, and they'll experience a large drop in status if they ever try to leave. All this, in turn, gives everyone a strong incentive to make sure everyone else remains loyal to the group. The peer pressure that results is likely to be intense.
Religions often take these processes to an extreme. Adherents scramble to signal commitment as a way of jockeying for local prestige. In this context, everyone is anxious to do and say the right things. Schelling points for "proper" beliefs and behaviors are established quickly, resulting in capricious orthodoxies and bizarre ritual practices. And because loyalty is what's at stake, the group will tend to prefer beliefs and behaviors that are costly to maintain and perform. Orthodox Jews spurn food from non-Kosher kitchens. Fundamentalist Christians deny evolution. Christian Scientists refuse blood transfusions. Mormons wear special underwear. And every religion asks for weekly devotion. In each of these "transactions," adherents sacrifice their status with outsiders as part of a calculated gambit to earn greater status among their co-religionists.
And when the conditions are just right — when the incentives to signal loyalty are strong enough, and the countervailing incentives weak enough — a community can undergo something like gravitational collapse. These groups then become perfectly insular communities, social black holes from which escape is all but impossible.
___
Recommended reading:
- Geeks, MOPs, and sociopaths in subculture evolution (David Chapman). A great illustration of prestige (cultural capital) and selling out vs. selling in.
- How to Legally Own Another Person (Nassim Taleb). Loyalty dynamics in employer/employee relationships.
Endnotes:
[1] teaming concerns. Other concerns include: evaluating potential teams (to decide which ones are worth joining), keeping track of existing team members' contributions, deciding whom to kick out of a team (and when and how), deciding when to leave a team, and of course working together as a team, i.e., leading and/or following, as appropriate.
[2] cults. I'm using "cult" here in the neutral, non-derogatory sense, meaning "a system of religious veneration and devotion directed toward a particular figure or object."